About the Center
Join Our Mailing List
Research
Policy
Education & Training
Frequently Asked Questions
Newsletter
Services
Surveys
Publications
Calendar of Events
Site Map

View All Policy Categories

Articles for
Federal

5 articles found. Page 1 of 1

The Federal Government's Role in Funding the Child Welfare System---in Plain Language©

The Struggle Between Families and Adoption Providers Over The Hague Convention

An Overview of Federal Adoption Policy Legislation: An Economic Perspective

Commentary

Legislative Update


View 1-5

Printer Friendly Version | EMail to A Friend

An Overview of Federal Adoption Policy Legislation: An Economic Perspective

Mary Eschelbach Hansen and Bradley A. Hansen

Until quite recently, most federal child welfare and adoption policy has focused on subsidizing the operations of state child welfare agencies and encouraging the adoption of children in foster care.  This raises issues related to federal spending and its effectiveness in encouraging desired outcomes.  The following is an excerpt from a research project currently underway at the Center. 

INTRODUCTION
Of the 556,000 children in foster care at the end of fiscal year 2000, 131,000 children were waiting for adoptive homes.  However, just 50,000 adoptions from foster care were finalized in fiscal year 2001.   At least 81,000 children waited into another year.  The majority of the waiting children had been in foster care for more than 30 months.  The children who were adopted in fiscal year 2001 waited an average of two years after becoming legally free for adoption before their adoption was finalized.   In each year since the mid-1970s, between 20 and 25 percent of children in foster care has needed an adoptive family, but despite growth in the number of adoptions in the U.S., the number of families who adopt through public agencies has never met more than about 40 percent of the need.  Many of the waiting children are never adopted.  This is not to say that adoption is rare.   According to a recent survey on attitudes regarding adoption, about two of every three Americans adults report that their lives have been touched by adoption.  One in three has considered adoption as a way to start or build a family.  Private and international adoption agencies have long waiting lists; agencies are sometimes so overwhelmed with inquires that they suspend their acceptance of applications by families altogether.  It is sadly ironic that the number of families in the U.S. who seek children through adoption is greater than the number of children in foster care who wait to be adopted.  Byron and Deoudes (2002) estimate that if one in every 500 of the adults who have considered adoption were to adopt a child from foster care, then the needs of all waiting children could be met.  In this paper we identify, in broad terms, the federal policy variables that are associated with success in meeting the needs of waiting children.

Both President Clinton and President Bush have taken steps to encourage increased adoptions from foster care,  and in 1997 Congress passed the Adoption and Safe Families Act, the first major federal reform of adoption and foster care since 1980.  Attempts to reform public policy should be informed by an understanding of the factors that influence the adoption decision and adoptive placement, but little economic research has been done on the factors that influence adoptions from foster care.  In the first section below we summarize federal efforts to encourage adoptions from foster care in the states.  We then present a model of demand for adoption services, and we present weighted least squares estimates explaining adoptions from foster care across the states using data for fiscal years 1996 and 1997.  We find that the demand for adoption services is sensitive to subsidy support; we estimate the elasticity of demand for adoption services with respect to the subsidy to be about one.  We also find evidence that the price of adoption from foster care relative to the price of alternatives has an effect on adoptions.  A brief conclusion summarizes the policy implications of our findings.

A BRIEF HISTORY OF FEDERAL INCENTIVES TO PROMOTE ADOPTION
Since 1978 Congress has tried to promote the adoption of children from foster care.  However, even in years when the number of adoptions rose, the number of waiting children rose faster.   As the number of waiting children in foster care climbed, Congress responded to the recurring “foster care crises” with new adoption incentive programs. 

The first federal adoption incentive was contained in the Child Abuse Prevention and Treatment and Adoption Reform Act of 1978 (P.L. 95-266 Section 203). The law created a discretionary grants program to fund state promotion of the adoption of children with so-called “special needs.” Though the grants program was small relative to later incentives, the introduction of the term “special needs” has had a significant impact on adoption.  Special needs are characteristics of a child that can make adoption more difficult.  Special needs can include physical, mental, learning and emotional disabilities (or risk of these conditions), older age, minority status, or membership in a sibling group that ought to be adopted together.  Most children who are adopted from foster care have one or more special needs.  States designate the conditions that constitute special needs in that state.  The definition of special needs is dynamic; states may change their definitions as circumstances change. 

The Adoption Assistance and Child Welfare Act of 1980 (P.L. 96-272), which instituted a wide range of changes in the child welfare system, created the first federal incentive aimed at families who adopt.  The Act amended Section IV-E of the Social Security Act to authorize monthly adoption assistance subsidies to families adopting children with special needs.  States determine their own level of adoption assistance subsidy support and are partially reimbursed through federal appropriations.

The Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981 created an itemized deduction of up to $1500 for qualified expenses relating to the adoption of children with special needs (P.L. 97-34 Section 125).  The Tax Reform Act of 1986 (P.L. 99-514) provided matching funds of up to $1,000 to states that pay the up-front expenses of the adoption of a child from foster care. 

The adoption tax deduction was replaced by the Adoption Tax Credit in 1996 (P.L. 104-188 Section 1807).  The Adoption Tax Credit was available beginning in tax year 1997 to any family finalizing an adoption from any source, including an adoption from foster care.  The credit could be taken against up to $5,000 in qualified expenses for adoption ($6,000 for the adoption of a child with special needs).  An income exclusion of up to $5,000 was also made available for adoptive parents whose employers offered reimbursement for adoption expenses.  In its study of utilization of the adoption tax credit, the Department of the Treasury found that only 15 percent of families who claimed the credit had adopted a child with special needs, and the tax benefits to these families was only eight percent of total benefits claimed (US Dept. of Treasury 2000, 2).  Expenses for adoption from foster care are small, usually zero, because most states use the 1986 provision of federal matching funds to pay the up-front cost of adoption for families.  The result is that most families who adopt children from foster care receive no benefits from the Adoption Tax Credit.

The Adoption and Safe Families Act of 1997 (P.L. 105-89) was the most wide-ranging reform of foster care and adoption policy since 1980.  The ASFA swung the focus of incentives from families to states.  States could earn bonus payments for increasing the number of adoptions from foster care.  Adoptions over the state’s goal earned the state a bonus of up to $4,000 each (up to $6,000 each for children with special needs).   Unless reauthorized when the 108th Congress convenes in January 2003, the ASFA bonus payments end with adoptions finalized in fiscal year 2002.  

The ASFA contained other provisions; most notably the law accelerated the process for foster care case review and the termination of parental rights.  These other provisions have been widely discussed in law and social work journals.   The ASFA also increased funding available for post-adoption services and added a new discretionary grants program that states could use for programs that support adoption-related goals.

The latest adoption incentive program began January 1, 2003.  The Tax Relief Act of 2001 (P.L. 107-16, Title II, Section 202) swings the focus of federal incentives back from the states to the family.  The Act institutes a $10,000 unqualified tax credit for each family who adopts a child with special needs.  The unqualified tax credit will go to families finalizing the adoption of a child with special needs after January 1, 2003.  The tax credit is not reimbursement of adoption expenses.  It is an outright gift worth a full year or more of tax-free income for most families.   In part because so few families who adopted children from foster care were able to utilize earlier adoption tax benefits, it is not known how families considering adoption will respond to the incentive of the unqualified tax credit.

To summarize, federal incentives for adoption from foster care have swung from a focus on the family, to a focus on the state, and back, without clear evidence on which is more effective.  This paper begins to fill the gap in our knowledge about how families respond to incentives to promote adoption.

A MODEL OF THE MARKET FOR ADOPTION SERVICES
Most economic research on adoption concerns the relinquishment of infants and their subsequent adoption. Economists have primarily been interested in explaining why there are so few infants available for adoption through private agencies, lawyers, and facilitators, while there are so many prospective adoptive families who seek healthy infants.  Medoff (1993) and Gennetian (1999) explore the determinants of relinquishment of infants by birth mothers, and compare the determinants of relinquishment relative to abortion.  Elizabeth Landes and Richard Posner (1978) develop an analysis of the market for infant adoption, with an eye towards recommending policy that would reduce the shortage of infants.  Posner (1992) expands on the argument.  Posner concludes that the birth parents, the adoptive parents, and the children would be better off if the price mechanism were allowed to function more freely.  Posner posits that fewer prospective adopters would seek infants if their adoption was more expensive.  He further argues that if birth mothers were fairly compensated more infants would be available; that is, Posner argues that the supply of infants available for adoption is upward sloping. 

The number of children in foster care with a goal of adoption does not depend on the price of adoption services.  Children in foster care are legally freed for adoption only when a court determines that their birth families cannot provide for their care.  Therefore, our model focuses on demand for adoption services.

We have chosen the phrase “demand for adoption services” purposefully.  Posner argues that the adoption market for infants is a market in which parental rights are exchanged. Critics such as Viviana Zelizer (1981) and Madelyn Freundlich (2000) denounce this stance as equivalent to baby-selling.  Our stance is closer to that of sociologists and social workers.  We do not model adoption as a market for a child, or a market where parental rights are sold.  Despite well-publicized aberrations, children who are adopted through agencies (public, private, and international), lawyers, and facilitators are not simply allocated to those who are most willing to pay.  Adoption is a professional service.  Prospective adoptive families pay to be matched with the children who they are well-suited to parent, either by the best judgment of the family or by the best judgment of a social worker.

An essential feature of the market for adoption services is its segmentation.  The market is segmented by the characteristics of the children to be adopted.  We see the segmentation of the market as an institutional feature that helps reduce search costs for prospective adoptive families.   Most private and international adoption agencies, adoption lawyers, and adoption facilitators promise to match families with healthy, light-skinned, young children or infants.  Most public agencies, alongside a limited number of private agencies that contract with public agencies, match families only with older children and children with special needs.

Families who consider adoption have obviously considered adding an additional child to their families.  Several possibilities exist: they may conceive a child (without or with medical intervention); they may engage a surrogate; they may foster a child; or they may adopt a child through one of the several agencies that provide adoption services.  

Let us limit our attention to the choice of adoption agency.  For simplicity, consider two types of adoption services, adoption services from a domestic public agency and an international agency.  Assume that the adoption services from the two agencies are perfect substitutes in the eyes of the family, and that there is less than perfect substitution between adopted children and all other goods.   Then household utility is:

u = v ( h(αP qP + αI qI), q2, …, qN)

where
h is the subutility function for consumption of adoption services;
qP is the number of children adopted through a domestic public agency;
qI is the number of children adopted through an international public agency; and
αi represents the expected characteristics of adoption services at the different agencies, including characteristics of the children they promise to place.
and q2,…, qN  are other goods consumed by the family.

The solution that maximizes family utility when there are only two sources of adoption services is easy to see because, given the assumptions, families will have linear indifference curves such as AB in figure 1.  The relative price of adoption through the two agencies is the slope of the budget constraint CB.  Families choose to adopt through the domestic public agency if the marginal rate of substitution is higher than the price of adoption services at the domestic public agency relative to the international agency, that is, if αP / αI  > pP / pI.  The lower the price of adoption services at the public agency relative to the price of adoption services at the international agency, the more likely any individual family will be to choose to adopt through the domestic public agency, and the more common adoptions from foster care will be in aggregate.

By all accounts, the price of international and private adoption services is quite high.  The Department of Treasury reports that the average cost of adoptions claimed by families on their 1998 tax returns was $9,876; 52 percent of families reported expenses greater than $10,000 (USDOT 2000, 3).  In contrast, almost all of the up-front costs of adoption from foster care are paid by states with help from the federal government, and the monthly adoption assistance subsidy is available (again from the states with federal help) for children with special needs.  The model predicts that states that offer greater subsidy support will have more adoptions of children from foster care, ceteris paribus.  In the next section we measure the importance of relative prices in adoption services, and we estimate the elasticity of demand for adoption services from public agencies with respect to the subsidies.

EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF DEMAND FOR ADOPTION SERVICES
To find the elasticity of demand for adoption services with respect to the subsidy, we estimate the straightforward model:

log Ai=a + b1 log Si + b2Xi + b3Yi+ ei,

where Ai is adoptions from foster care in state i , Si is the adoption assistance subsidy support, and ei is an error term.  The vector X contains information about substitutes for adoption from foster care, plus other variables that affect demand for waiting children such as income and age structure of the state population. 

 Recall that adoption is a professional service that matches families with children.  The number of adoptions across the states is likely to vary with the ability of the states to match waiting children with families.  The ability of a state to match waiting children with families will depend on child welfare resources, especially available social worker time, characteristics of the population of the states, and characteristics of the waiting children in the states.  These are the variables in the vector Y.  

The definitions and descriptive statistics of the variables used in the estimation appear in table 1, and the weighted least squares regression results appear in table 2. 

Adoptions from Foster Care
The number of adoptions from foster care in each state during the federal fiscal year is reported to the Department of Health and Human Services, Administration for Children and Families.   The finalization of the adoption of a waiting child is a legal procedure that takes several months to more than a year to complete.  After a child is placed in the home of her adoptive family, there is generally a waiting period before the family may file a petition asking the court to finalize the adoption.  The length of the waiting period varies by state.  The date that the adoption is finalized is also subject to influences beyond the control of either social workers or adoptive families (for instance, court delays).  For these reasons we introduce a time lag into the model.  We estimate the model using the number of adoptions finalized in fiscal year 1997, while the independent variables are for 1996 when the decision about adoption was made.

As might be expected, there is great variation in the number of adoptions from foster care between the states.   The average number of adoptions from foster care in 1997 is 608; the standard deviation is 928.  Part of the reason for the large standard deviation is the difference in the size of the states.  In order to remove the effect of the size of the state, we use as our dependent variable adoptions per 100,000 persons in the state.    Adoptions per 100,000 average 11.9, and have standard deviation of 14.8.

Adoption Assistance Subsidy
The first type of subsidy for adoption that we consider is the monthly adoption assistance subsidy, which was introduced into federal law in 1980 and aims to reduce the marginal cost of raising an adopted child with special needs.  States can, and do, supplement the federal adoption assistance subsidy.  The average of the regular adoption assistance subsidy paid by the states to a family in support of a nine-year-old adopted child was $361 per month in 1996, with a standard deviation of $116.  After adjusting for variations in the cost of living between states, the standard deviations of the monthly subsidy rates falls to $82. 

In 1999 over 88 percent of adoption agreements for waiting children included monthly adoption assistance subsidy payments (USGAO 2002).  There is indirect evidence that the adoption assistance subsidy is effective.  A report commissioned by the Department of Health and Human Services on the early implementation of the adoption assistance subsidy reports that, of families who adopted from foster care in the mid-1980s, 29 percent said that they would have had had difficulty adopting their child(ren) without the subsidy, and 35 percent said the availability of the subsidy had a positive influence on their decision to adopt (Sedlack and Broadhurst 1993, 6-58 and 6-59). 

Sedlack and Broadhurst also find that children adopted with subsidies exited foster care to their adoptive families more quickly than children adopted without subsidy.  Avery and Mont (1992, 1997) concur, finding that adoption assistance subsidies reduce waiting times for children with special needs in their study of New York State.  Neither study looks for a correlation between adoption assistance subsidy support and the number of adoptive placements.

We find a positive and statistically significant elasticity of demand for adoption services with respect to basic adoption assistance subsidy rates.  Table 2 shows the range of performance of our model.  Column (1) shows the specification in which we include on the right hand side only the relevant policy variables.  Column (2) controls for all identified determinants of demand for adoption services.  Our elasticity estimates range from 0.99 to 1.54.  In these and all of the other specifications of the model that we tried, the coefficient representing the elasticity was statistically significant.

Suppose that the true elasticity of demand with respect to the subsidy is one.  Then an increase in the average adoption assistance subsidy of $3.60 per month per child would increase the number of adoptions by about 1.2 per 100,000 population.  Nationally, this adds up to 3,000 additional adoptions (based on the national population of about 260 million in 1996) at a cost of about $1.3 million annually.  The 95 percent confidence interval of the elasticity estimate is [0.47, 2.61], so the cost of 3,000 additional adoptions may be as large as $3 million or as small as $500,000. 

Subsidy of Up-Front Cost of Adoption
As discussed above, in addition to the monthly adoption assistance subsidy, federal law encourages states to subsidize the up-front cost of adoption from foster care, including the cost of legal fees.  The subsidy of up-front cost is offered in the form of matching funds to the states, up to $1,000 per adoption.  That is, to utilize the full federal subsidy, the state must reimburse families up to $2,000.  Most, but not all, states utilize the full amount of federal matching funds; the average maximum subsidy for up-front adoption expenses is $1,587.  We include a dichotomous variable that equals one if the state chooses not to utilize the full federal subsidy.  States that do not reimburse the full $2,000 of the up-front costs of adoptions have fewer adoptions from foster care, but the coefficient is not statistically significant.  There is correlation, however, between offering a high monthly adoption assistance subsidy and offering the full $2,000 of reimbursement of up-front costs, so the standard errors may be inflated. 

Substitutes for Adoption of Waiting Children
The substitutes for adoption services for waiting children include infertility treatment, surrogacy, foster parenting, and private and international agency adoption services, as well as more traditional conception and child birth practices.  We included in our model the fertility rate and the percent of all unrelated adoptions with private agency involvement.  The signs of the coefficients on these independent variables are, as expected, negative.   

The coefficient on the percent of intercountry adoptions is negative and statistically significant.  The strong negative relationship between intercountry adoption and adoption from domestic foster care underscores the importance of considering the substitutes for adoption from foster care in the formulation of public policy.  In 1996, intercountry adoptions comprised 16.6% of unrelated adoptions.  In1996 the Adoption Tax Credit lowered the price of adoption services at international agencies relative to the price of adoption services at domestic public agencies.  From 1996 through 1999, the number of orphan visas issued by the U.S. State Department increased 45 percent.   How many more children waiting in foster care might have been adopted if the tax code had not altered relative prices?

Of particular interest as a substitute for the adoption of waiting children is foster care. A majority of waiting children are adopted by their foster parents and a significant (and increasing) number are adopted by kin who also serve as foster parents.   Many potential adoptive families clearly face a choice between parenting through adoption and parenting through long-term foster care.  On average, foster care board rates are greater than adoption subsidy rates: $371 compared to $360.  Twenty-five states set basic adoption assistance rates equal to the foster care board rate; seven states set adoption assistance subsidies above foster care board rates.  We test to see if setting adoption subsidy rates above foster care board rates increases the number of adoptions.  As expected, the estimated effect is positive.  This finding again underscores the importance of further study of relative prices and incentives in child welfare.  We would not argue that foster care board rates should be lowered, of course, since foster care board rates do not even equal the average amount spent by families in support of their children (Laws and OÂ’Hanlon 1999, 28-29).  We would argue, however, that states ought to pay close attention to the matter of the adoption assistance rate relative to the foster care board rate

Median Income and Demographics

Other variables that may affect the demand for waiting children are the income and age of the population. We include the median household income for each state as our measure of income.  The median household income in the states was $37,995, with a standard deviation of $5,594.  The National Survey of Family Growth reveals that women with higher incomes are more likely to have adopted a child (Chandra et al. 1999, 3).  We find positive correlation between the natural log of median income and adoptions per 100,000. 

We include the percentage of the population between 25 and 44 years of age as a measure of the proportion of the population that is likely to be building families.  A larger proportion of the population in this age range is associated with a more adoptions from foster care.

Child Welfare Spending
Again, we view adoption as a professional service that matches families with children.  Matching requires resources, especially social worker time.  A public adoption agency may have insufficient resources to match waiting children with potential adoptive families in a timely manner.  If limited resources results in high caseloads, social workers may find that after they provide emergency services to children, reunification services to birth families, and support services to foster families, they have little time remaining to provide adoption services.  Evidence to support this hypothesis comes from recent federal funding initiatives.  When states acquired additional funding for child welfare services under the 1997 Adoption and Safe Families Act, 13 of 46 states used some or all of their funds to hire or contract additional social work staff (USGAO 2002, 33).

Our measure of child welfare resources is 1996 appropriations for child welfare services in each state, as collected by the Urban Institute.  The Urban Institute reports spending on adoption and spending foster care; however, by 1996 many states had begun to provide concurrent planning for children in foster care.  Concurrent planning means that a social worker plans simultaneously for a child’s reunification with birth parents and for a backup - frequently for adoption - should reunification efforts prove fruitless.  To a great extent it is impossible to clearly divide child welfare spending into discrete adoption and foster care categories.  Moreover, spending on adoption includes adoption assistance subsidies, which are already included in our estimate.  

Child welfare spending per child in foster care varied greatly between the states.  The average child welfare spending per child in foster care was $13,996, and the standard deviation was $8,799.  Despite the considerable variation, child welfare spending does not appear to influence adoptions from foster care.  Even if we attribute, as we may, the low level of statistical significance of the coefficient to multi-colinearity, the size of the coefficient is so small that to increase adoptions per 100,000 by one would require additional child welfare expenditures in the representative state of about $1,100 per child in care.  The average number of children in foster care in 1996 was 10,442.  Therefore, the representative state would need additional appropriations of at least $11.5 million annually, or more than a 10 percent increase over average state spending on child welfare services in 1996.

African-American and Native American Presence

Previous studies of adoption from foster care have suggested that race is a particularly important factor influencing the ability of social workers to make matches between families and waiting children.  Both the race of potential adoptive families and the race of waiting children have been cited as relevant. Some researchers (most recently by Melosh (2002)) have suggested that African American families eschew formal adoption.  It is said that, when circumstances require, African Americans prefer to use informal networks of extended family care.  We therefore control for the size of the African American community, and we expect that the greater the percentage of African Americans in the state population, the lower the adoption rate will be.  The sign of the coefficient confirms our expectations, but the estimated coefficient is small and not statistically significant.

Finally, we consider the characteristics of the foster care population.  We control for the number of Native American children in foster care because placements of Native American children are regulated by the Indian Child Welfare Act.  The ICWA requires that Native American children be placed for adoption within the tribe whenever possible, and therefore we expect states with large populations of Native American children in foster care to have lower adoption rates.  We include a dichotomous variable indicating whether Native American children comprise 10 percent or more of the foster care population in the state.  We find that the IWCA does not appear to limit the ability of states to place waiting children with adoptive families.  In fact, states with more

Native American children in care have more adoptions from foster care.
Finally, discrimination on the basis of race may prevent the adoption of waiting children.  It is mainly Caucasian families who adopt a child whom they do not know; waiting children are mainly African American and Hispanic.  If Caucasian families are unwilling to adopt children of color, it will be more difficult to match waiting children with adoptive families.  Even before transracial adoption became a hotbed of conflict within the field of social work in the 1970s and 1980s, surveys suggested that race of the child was a particularly important area of concern for adoptive families.  More recent surveys of adoptive families find a much smaller role for race, but some families still express strong preferences about the race, age, number of siblings and disabilities of children they are willing to adopt.

Just as families may have preferences about appropriate matches in adoption, social workers may have their own opinions about matching children and families with certain characteristics.  Sherri Kossoudji (1989, 1997) and Judy Fenster (2000) raise some important questions about racial bias in child welfare practice.  Using Michigan Department of Social Services data on foster care case openings and closings, Kossoudji finds that African American children who cannot be reunified with their birth families move towards permanency more slowly than Caucasian children.  Fenster finds negative attitudes towards transracial adoption are more common among African American social workers than among white social workers.  Despite federal efforts to remove race from the list of considerations in adoption from foster care (see footnote 9), few transracial placements are made for waiting children.   In a survey of families in California who adopted in the 1980s, 64 percent said they were willing to adopt a black child, but only five percent of the willing families actually adopted transracially (Brooks and James 2002).  The National Adoption Information Clearinghouse reports that an estimated 15 percent of the 36,000 adoptions of waiting children in fiscal year 1998 were transracial or transcultural adoptions.

We were therefore surprised, and encouraged, to find that states with a greater concentration of African American children in foster care have more adoptions from foster care.  More research into the reasons for the unexpected positive correlation is required.  Possibly states with higher concentrations of waiting children who are African American have been more successful at developing strategies for matching the children to families or for recruiting prospective adoptive families.  

CONCLUSION
We began this paper by arguing that child welfare policy has not been well informed by  economics.  While many questions about adoption policy remain to be answered, our study of adoption from foster care provides at least three important insights for economists and policymakers concerned with child welfare.  First, adoption incentives to families work.  Subsidies are an effective way to increase adoptions of waiting children.  Second, families respond not only to the subsidy for adoption of children with special needs, but also to the price of adoption from foster care relative to substitutes such as long-term foster care and intercountry adoption.  Policymakers who seek to encourage adoptions from foster care must simultaneously consider policy regarding the alternatives.  For example, policies such as tax credits that go primarily towards families who adopt through private or intercountry agencies are likely to reduce adoptions from foster care.   Finally, differences in child welfare spending do not appear to explain any of the differences in adoptions from foster care.  More research on family recruitment and the matching process in adoption is needed. 

Table 1
Summary Statistics

 Continuous Variables   N  State Average    Standard Deviation
 Adoptions from Foster Care in 1997 (a)  51  608 928 
 Adoptions per 100k Population (b) 51   11.9  14.8
 Monthly Adoption Assistance Subsidy for 9-year-old (c)  50  $360  $103
 Cost-of-Living Adjusted Adoption Assistance Subsidy (d)  50  $360  $82
 Births per 1000 Women Age 15-44 (b)  51  63.7  6.98
 Private Adoptions as% of All Unrelated Adoptions (g)  51  61.3%  20.4
 Intercountry Adoption as % of All Unrelated Adoptions (g)  51  16.6%  8.82
 Median Income (b)  51  $37,995  $5,594
 Percent of Population Age 25-44 in 1996 (b)  51  31.2%  1.96
 Foster Care Board Rate for 9-year-old (c)  50  $371  $81
 Child Welfare Spending in 1996 (e)  49  $130 mil  $240 mil
 Child Welfare Spending per Child in Foster Care (f)  49  $13,996  $8,799
 African Americans as a Percent of Population (h)  51  11.2%  12.8
 African Americans as a Percent of Foster Care Population (f)  40  33.1%  23.5
       
 Dichotomous Variables    Yes No 
 Adoption Subsidy > Foster Care Board Rate  51  7 44 
 Reimbursement of adoption expense < $2000 (i)  48  20 28 
 Native Americans >= 10 Percent of Foster Care Population (f)  51  17 34 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 


Notes and Sources:
a. U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Administration for Children and Families, Children’s Bureau, "Adoptions of Children with Public Child Welfare Agency Involvement by State, revised May 18, 2001," http://www.acf.dhhs.gov/programs/cb (last accessed June 1, 2002).
b. Basic population statistics from U.S. Census Bureau, Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1997.
c. Laws and O’Hanlon (1999).
d.  Cost of living index for 1995 from American Federation of Teachers, "AFT Interstate Cost of Living Index," http://www.aft.org/research/salary/stgrave/col/97.htm (last accessed January 20, 2003). 
e. Urban Institute, "Assessing the New Federalism Databases, State Database," http://www.urban.org/content/Research/Databases/Databases.htm (last accessed January 5, 2003).
f. Foster Care population data from Child Welfare League of America, National Data Analysis System, http://ndas.cwla.org/ (last accessed January 5, 2003).
g. National Committee on Adoption (1999).
h. Demographic statistics by race from U.S. Census Bureau, Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1998.
i. North American Council on Adoptable Children, "Reimbursement of Non-Recurring Adoption Expenses," http://www.finallyfamily.com/reimbursement.htm (last accessed June 1, 2002).
 
Table 2

Determinants of Adoptions from Foster Care

Dependent Variable:  Log of the Number of Adoptions per 100K Population in 1997

   (1)  (2)
 Log of C-O-L Adjusted Adoption Assistance Subsidy  0.99* 1.54* 
   (.48) (0.51) 
 Up-front Costs < $2k -0.02 -0.04 
  (0.18) (0.17) 
 Adoption Subsidy > Foster Care Rate 0.39  0.05 
  (0.32)  (0.33) 
 Births Per 1000 Women Age 15-44   -0.12 
     (0.02)
 Private Adoptions    -0.01
     (0.01)
 Intercountry Adoptions    -0.03*
     (0.13)
 Log of Median Income    1.58
     (1.45)
 Percent of Pop. Age 25-44    0.03
   

 (0.12)

 Log of Child Welfare Spending per Child  0.01  0.12
   (0.15)  (0.14)
 African Americans as % of Population    -0.01
     (0.02)
 African Americans as % of Foster Care Pop.    0.01
    (0.01) 
 Native Americans >= 10% of Foster Care Pop.    0.34
     (0.20)
 N  43  34
 R-Squared  0.27  0.63
 F  3.07  9.54

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 


Notes:  Weighted by state population; standard errors in parentheses, adjusted for heteroskedasticity.  * indicates statistical significance at the 95 percent level.  Incomplete data for CA, DE, IA, HA, MD, PA, TX, and VA.  Additional states omitted from specification (2) are CO, DC, KS, MT, ND, NE, OH, OR, and WY.
Sources:  See table 2.
 
Figure 1

Choice of Adoption Services


REFERENCES
Adler, Libby S. (2001). The meanings of permanence: A critical analysis of the adoption and safe families act of 1997. 38 Harvard Journal on Legislation 1.

Avery, Rosemary (1996). Adoption assistance under P.L. 96-272: A policy analysis. Children and Youth Services Review 18(3): 1-31.

Avery, Rosemary and Daniel Mont (1992). Financial support of children involved in special needs adoption: A policy evaluation.  Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 11: 419-441.

Avery, Rosemary and Daniel Mont (1997). Federal financial support of special needs adoption. In Rosemary Avery (ed.), Adoption Policy and Special Needs Children (New York: Auburn House).

Brooks, Devon and Sigrid James (2002). Willingness to adopt black foster children: Implications for child welfare policy and recruitment of adoptive families. Manuscript, University of Southern California.

Byron, Jeff and Georgia Deoudes (2002). 2002 national adoption attitudes survey. Presented at the Child Welfare League of America, National Adoption Conference, November 2002, representing the Dave Thomas Foundation for Adoption and the Evan B. Donaldson Adoption Institute (http://www.davethomasfoundation.org/ and http://www.adoptioninstitute.org/). 

Campbell, C., and S.W. Downs (1987). The impact of economic incentives of foster parents, Social Service Review (December): 599-609.

Chandra, Anjani et al. (1999). Adoption, adoption seeking, and relinquishment for adoption in the United States. Advance Data No. 306 from Vital Health Statistics Centers for Disease Control and Prevention/National Center for Health Statistics.

Christian, Stephen M. (1999). 1998 State Legislative Responses to the Adoption and Safe Families Act of 1997 (Denver, CO: National Conference of State Legislatures).

Daniels, Ken R. (1994).  Adopiton and Donor Insemination: Factors Influencing CouplesÂ’ Choices. Child Welfare 73(1): 5-14.

Fenster, Judy (2000), The psychology and politics of transracial adoption: A survey of social worker attitudes. Manuscript presented at the International Society of Political Psychology, 23rd Annual Scientific Meeting (Seattle, WA).

Freundlich, Madelyn (2000). The Market Forces in Adoption (Washington, DC: The Child Welfare League of America for the Evan B. Donaldson Adoption Institute).

Gennetian, Lisa A. (1999), The supply of infants relinquished for adoption: Did access to abortion make a difference? Economic Inquiry 37(3): 412-431.

Guggenheim, Martin (1999). The foster care dilemma and what to do about it. 2 University of Pennsylvania Journal of Constitutional Law 141.

Kossoudji, Sherrie A (1989). Pride and prejudice: CultureÂ’s role in markets, In Steven Shulamn and William Darity (eds.), The Question of Discrimination: Racial Inequality in the U.S. Labor Market (Middletown: Wesleyan University Press).

Kossoudji, Sherrie A. (1997). Racial aspects of the move to adoption. In Rosemary Avery (ed.), Adoption Policy and Special Needs Children (New York: Auburn House): 13-34.

Landes, Elizabeth M and Richard A. Posner (1978), The economics of the baby shortage.  7 Journal of Legal Studies 339.

Laws, Rita and Timothy OÂ’Hanlon (1999), Adoption and Financial Assistance (Westport, CT: Bergin and Garvey)

Maza, Penelope (1999). Recent data on the number of adoptions of foster children. Adoption Quarterly 32(2): 71-81.

Maza, Penolope  (2002). Is the adoption and safe families act doing what it is supposed to do? Manuscript presented at Child Welfare League of America, National Adoption Conference, November 7, 2002. 

Medoff, Marshall H. (1993), An Empirical Analysis of Adoption, Economic Inquiry 31(January): 59-70.

Melosh, Barbara (2002), Strangers and Kin: The American Way of Adoption (Cambridge: Harvard University Press).

National Committee for Adoption (1999).  Adoption Factbook (Washington: National Committee for Adoption).

Pertman, Adam (2000).  Adoption Nation (New York: Basic Books).

Posner, Richard (1992). Sex and Reason (Cambridge: Harvard University Press).

Sedlack, Andrea, and Diane Broadhurst (1993). Study of Adoption Assistance Impact and Outcomes: Final Report.  Submitted to the Administrtion for Children, Youth and Families, DHHS, Contract No. 105-89-1607.

Shughart, William F and William F. Chappell, Fostering the Demand for Adoptions: An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of orphanages and Foster Care on Adoptions in the United States. In Richard B. McKenzie (ed.), Rethinking Orphanages for the 21st Century (Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage 1999).

Simon, Julian I. (1975), The effect of foster-care payment levels on the number of foster children given homes. Social Service Review 49(3): 405-11.

Simon, Rita J., Howard Altstein, and Maryhold S. Melli (1994), The Case for Transracial Adoption (Washington: The American University Press).

Spar, Karen (1997). Adoption promotion legislation in the 105th Congress. Congressional Reporting Service Report for Congress, updated Nov. 24, 1997. 

Stein, Theodore J. (2000). The Adoption and Safe Families Act: Creating a false dichotomy between parentsÂ’ and childrenÂ’s rights. Families in Society: The Journal of Contemporary Human Services, 81(6): 586-592

Stolley, Kathy S. (1993), Statistics on adoption in the United States. The Future of Children: Adoption 3(1): 26-42.

United States Department of Health and Human Services (1997). Administration for Children and Families, Adoption 2002: A response to the presidential executive memorandum on adoption issued Dec. 14, 1996. Feb. 1997 (accessed at http://www.acf.dhhs.gov/programs/cb/ publications/adopt02/02final.htm, last visited 19 November 2001).

United States Department of Health and Human Service (1998).  Analysis of State Child Welfare Data: VCIS Survey Data from 1990 through 1994: (Washington DC: Caliber 1998). 

United States Department of Health and Human Service (2000).  Press release September 20, 2000: HHS Adopiton Awards Bonuses and Grants Available online: www.hhs.gov/news/press/2000pres/200000920.html.

United States Department of Health and Human Service (2002), Administration for Children and Families, ChildrenÂ’s Bureau, Initiatives: overcoming barriers to interstate adoptions. http://www.acf.hhs.gov/programs/cb/initiatives /photolts/sect4.htm#barriers.

United States Department of the Treasury (2000). Report to the Congress on Tax Benefits for Adoption (October 3, 2000) as per Small Business Job Protection Act of 1996 (P.L. 104-888, section 1807(d)).

United States General Accounting Office (1999). Foster Care:  HHS Could Better Facilitate the Interjurisdictional Adoption Process (GAO/HEHS-00-12).

United States General Accounting Office (2002). Foster Care: Recent Legislation Helps States Focus on Finding Permanent Home for Children by Long-Standing Barriers Remain (GAO-02-585, June 2002).

Zelizer, Viviana A. (1981). Pricing the Priceless Child: The Changing Social Value of Children (New York: Basic Books).

 

 

Home | About The Center | Join Our Mailing List | Research | Policy | Education & Training | FAQs | Newsletter
Services | Surveys | Publications | Calendar of Events | Links | Site Map | Contact Us

© Copyright 2002 Center for Adoption Research
Carol Curtis, Webmaster
Webmaster | Site Design Credits | Privacy Statement