Governor Tom Ridge is seeking new sources of revenue for funding new initiatives.
Pennsylvanians have a business, the stores of the Pennsylvania Liquor Control Board, they
think they may want to sell in order to help the Governor pay for his initiatives. In
private industry this would present no special difficulty. Business owners in the private
sector work with an accountant, a lawyer, and a business broker to value the firm fairly
and market the business. Those involved will look at the profitability of the firm, the
profitability of competitors and the opportunities for growth. The business broker finds a
buyer with the requisite qualifications. The seller and buyer bargain over the asking
price. If everyone has done their job, then the seller can be fairly confident that the
price he receives will be very close to the value of the firm to the new owner.
The business Pennsylvanians think they want to sell has never been operated in the private
sector in their state. Within the state there are no private sector counterparts against
which to compare the business for the purpose of valuation. The owners of the business,
all of the residents of the Commonwealth, are so widely dispersed that management,
composed of career civil servants, has been able to set its own agenda. Such behavior is
consistent with economic theory. That agenda may or may not have been profit maximization.
This compounds the valuation problem. There is no assurance that if the business is sold
in the conventional manner that the Commonwealth will receive a price close to its value
to the new owners.
In surveying the market for businesses, goods and services, a common feature stands out.
When goods are not standardized, when the intrinsic value of the good is uncertain, or
when the market clearing prices are highly unstable, posted prices work poorly, and
auctions are usually preferred (McAfee and Preston, 1987).
In the private sector there are many goods whose intrinsic value is uncertain, but which
are traded every day. Wines are auctioned regularly in California, New York, and in the
major cities of Europe. The wines at auction are not always rare, aged vintages with a
known historical quality. New vintages, which may not be consumed for years, are also sold
at auction. The buyers try to value the new vintages prospectively on the basis of their
knowledge of weather during the growing season and the future of wine drinkers'
preferences for varietals of a given type.
Government bonds are auctioned every week in many countries of the world. Their present
value depends on the uncertain course of future interest rates and exchange rates.
Different individuals forecast the future of interest rates differently, so those bonds
have different values to each person in the market. If the government were to set a fixed
take-it-or-leave-it price, the way brooms are sold at Home Depot, they could not know
whether they have gotten the best (highest) possible price.
National governments around the world have used auctions to sell 'commodities' which are
being brought to the market for the first time. In these cases the government cannot
possibly know how the business community will value the good. The U.S., Australia and New
Zealand have all used auctions to sell the rights to radio, TV, and telephone signals on
different bands of the magnetic spectrum.
This paper proposes the use of an auction to transfer the rights to the retail
distribution of wine and liquor in Pennsylvania. In the next section we briefly reprise
the case for privatization. We then survey the theory of auctions and their design. The
West Virginia experience is reviewed and used to develop an empirical model for valuing
the likely price to be fetched by the Pennsylvania system. Concluding remarks include
recommendations for auction procedures and a forecast of the results of such an auction.
In posing the question of whether the state should privatize liquor and wine
distribution, one should first consider the working premises of those opposing such a
move. The first one seems to be that alcohol consumption is intrinsically bad for the
individual and society. It cannot be denied that there are adverse health consequences
from the excess intake of alcohol. The individual tales of the personal costs of alcohol
abuse are sad and compelling. At the same time, there are only a handful of countries
around the world which are willing to incur the incremental cost of total prohibition in
order to save a small minority from the costs of their abuse. Societies in the rest of the
world rely on different degrees of government control and private distribution to make
alcohol beverages available. The reason for this is quite simple. There is just no easily
interpreted empirical evidence to suggest that private distribution is more damaging to
the public weal than government monopoly.
Since alcohol beverages are made available to the public, the obvious follow on question
is the prevention of alcohol abuse and the consequent drunk driving, violence and work
related injury. Addressing this issue is an industry in itself, with its own foundations,
working groups and journals. Nowhere in the alcohol beverage literature is it widely
concluded that government ownership of the alcohol beverage distribution system is a
necessary adjunct of the regulation of consumption (Holder, 1993).
Over the last decade Iowa, West Virginia and Alberta, Canada have all privatized some or
all of their alcohol distribution system. To one degree or another all three of them
recognized the disciplinary force of the private sector as the best way to promote
economic efficiency. The private sector could be relied upon to locate retail outlets in
desirable locations, to stock stores with products desired by consumers, and to charge
prices reflecting demand in the market. It was also recognized that privatization would be
a direct way to promote entrepreneurship in the state or province. Privatization was seen
as a way to increase public revenues through the periodic sale of licenses and recurring
sales tax revenues. In many respects, all of these goals have been met.
In Alberta where taxes are excise based, retail prices have fallen on high end items and
risen on low end items since retail distribution was privatized in 1993. A sales weighted
price index may have indeed risen. The variety of products increased 72% after
privatization. Excise tax revenues have exceeded expectations. Without more time it is not
possible to determine if consumption is up due to the stocking effect of the sudden
tripling in the number of outlets. Liquor retail employment rose from 1800 to 3000 within
two years of privatization (Swaine, 1995).
Within a year of privatization in Iowa prices had risen about 6%. When adjusted for the
rise in disposable income and the rise in the price level, the real increase was
negligible. The price trend of wine and liquor was similar in other states for the same
period. The privatization had no lasting impact on the overall downward trend in
consumption in the state. There was also no perceived increase in cross border sales as a
result of the price increase attributable to privatization (Fitzgerald and Mulford, 1993).
The more recent West Virginia experience is discussed below.
The nay sayers fear a great increase in alcohol beverage consumption. The empirical debate
on increased consumption attributable to privatization is ongoing and the results are
mixed. both sides agree that greater off-premise outlet density has a more than
proportionate effect on public drunkenness. Otherwise increasing the density of outlets
seems to have little impact on consumption. For cirrhosis and per capita sales the
relationship to outlet density is numerically weak, but positive. The weak relationships
of income and price to the consumption of alcoholic beverages are direct and inverse,
respectively. The effects of days and hours of availability are also not unequivocal.
Compliance with alcohol laws seems greater in states with a monopoly regulator. In short,
a privatization which does not greatly alter the number of outlets or the days and hours
of operation is not likely to alter the overall consumption of alcohol in the state.
A seller takes a good to auction because she cannot determine ex ante the value
that consumers would assign to the good. When goods are sold to all comers at a fixed
price there will be a difference between the price paid and the buyers' valuation of the
good. That difference is known as consumer surplus. Firms are in the business of trying to
capture as much of that surplus as possible. Under a wide range of circumstances, there is
no other mechanism which can capture a greater share of the consumer surplus for the
seller than an auction (Wang, 1993).
To be successful at auction, the seller must be able to make a credible commitment that
she will not change her procedures after seeing the bid(s). That is, if there is a bid
which would have been acceptable under the announced rules of the auction, the seller
cannot then renege. It is also necessary that the seller does not know the bidders'
valuations. If the seller knows the bidders' valuations then she will simply announce a
price to extract the highest possible value.
There are four common types of auctions used in the world today. In the open, oral English
auction the price is successively raised by the auctioneer until only one bidder
remains. The winning bidder pays a price which is below his own valuation of the good, but
is at least equal to the value assigned by the next-to-last bidder. This auction is
efficient in the sense that the good will go to the bidder who values it most highly. This
type of auction is quite common in the United States and is used to sell everything from
stocks, to antiques and art, to wine.
In the open, oral Dutch auction the auctioneer starts at a high price, so high that
no one could conceivably agree to it. The price is then successively lowered until one
bidder accepts the current price. Again, the good will be assigned to the person who
values it most highly. The price paid will be below that valuation, but above the
valuation of the next highest participant. This type of auction is used in Europe to sell
fresh cut flowers, fish and other commodities.
In the first-price sealed-bid auction, potential buyers submit sealed bids. The
highest bidder is awarded the good for the price she bid. There are scenarios under which
this auction form is not efficient. Nevertheless, it is used in many venues. In the U.S.
it has been used to auction everything from timber, to oil exploration rights, to alcohol
beverage distribution rights.
In the second-price sealed-bid auction, bidders submit bids having been told that
the highest bidder gets the item but pays only the amount of the second highest bid.
Again, this auction form can produce a result in which the person with the greatest
valuation does not win the auction. This auction form has been used in the sale of foreign
exchange, the magnetic spectrum and mineral rights.
Within each of these four basic types of auction there are a number of variations. In some
instances the seller announces a reserve price. A bid must come in above the reserve price
or the good is withdrawn. Typically a reserve price is used when the good has some value
in use to the seller.
To limit collusion and to keep the auction moving, bidders may be allowed only a limited
time to submit their bids. The effect of collusion is to reduce the seller's ability to
narrow the difference between the value of the good to the buyer and the price she must
pay for the good. In the same spirit there may be a minimum increment to the highest
existing bid in an English auction.
Bidders may be charged an entry fee for the right to participate in the auction. This
practice is used to make sure that participants are both serious and qualified bidders. In
some instances the participant forfeits her entry fee if she defaults on a winning bid.
The seller may require not only a purchase price but a royalty to measure the true value
of the good or the intensity of its use. This mechanism is used in auctioning oil
exploration rights. The winning bidder pays a fee for the right to explore. Once
production begins the firm pays a portion of the gross revenue from the well to the
government. Within this there are really three forms. Bidders may bid on the one time fee,
taking the royalty as fixed. They may take the fee as fixed and bid on the royalty. Or
they may construct a bid on both parts.
Of course, there is a moral hazard problem in the use of the one time fee and royalty
format. The conventional use of 'moral hazard' is in the study of insurance. Selling the
owner of a building a fire insurance policy provides an incentive for the owner to be less
cautious in securing his building against fire. The concept is applicable in auction
markets as well. For example, the seller cannot count on the oil wildcatter to exploit the
successful oil well to its fullest extent since he must share the proceeds of his efforts
with the seller of the good. There is a way to circumvent this. Instead of selling the
good the seller might offer shares in the good. In this way the success of the winning
bidder is inextricably tied to the seller.
Any of these auction forms can be used to sell goods for which more than one unit is
available. In multi-unit auctions, in which the bidder makes an offer on both price and
quantity, the auction may be either competitive or discriminatory. In a competitive
auction each bidder gets his quantity at the price offered by the lowest bid still found
acceptable to the seller. In a discriminatory auction each bidder pays his own bid price.
A Benchmark Auction Model:
In order to compare and contrast the outcomes of the four auction forms, economists
have developed a benchmark auction model. The assumptions of the model are: 1. The bidders
are risk neutral. That is, they would be indifferent between, say, being given $.50 in
cash or receiving $1.00 when a coin toss came up heads and receiving nothing when it came
up tails.
2. Bidders have independent private values. That is, each of them values the good
intrinsically, but they don't know the valuations assigned by their competitors. This
assumption is most applicable at an antiques auction in which the participants are not
dealers, so all are anticipating buying the good for their own use, not for resale.
3. The bidders are symmetric. In the formation of their private, independent values, the
bidders are not distinguishable from one another. For example, in bidding for a rare
vintage of wine both bidders believe that they can resell the bottle or buy it elsewhere
for $100 with probability .6 and $150 with probability .4. Before bidding they each get a
draw from the probability distribution, but keep knowledge of it to themselves.
4. The payment is a function of bids alone. This eliminates consideration of entry fees,
penalties and royalties. The assumption is more for reasons of simplicity, as none of
these charges change the results.
Under these four assumptions each prospective buyer will bid something less than his true
valuation of the good. The difference is the economic rent captured by the successful
bidder. A successful bidder will have bid just enough to equal the value assigned to the
good by the person with the second highest valuation, knowing that the number two person
will also bid less than his true valuation by the same logic.
Whether or not we invoke any of the assumptions, the Dutch auction and the first-price
sealed-bid auction will yield the same revenue outcome, on average. The intuition is that
no participant reveals his valuation to the others until the good is assigned to the
winner. Then it is too late to change one's bid if one had been trying to bid
strategically. Hence, there is no incentive to dissemble, and everyone bids truthfully.
If all four of the assumptions are imposed then each of the four possible auctions yields
the same expected revenue to the seller. This is known as the revenue equivalence theorem.
However, the variance of the revenue to the seller is lower in the English and second
price formats than in the Dutch and first price formats. Thus, the latter two auction
forms are more risky for the seller.
It helps the seller to have more widespread participation (more bidders) in the auction.
Increasing the number of bidders will increase the seller's expected revenue from the
auction. The intuition is that the extra competition from more participants forces
everyone to bid closer to their true valuation in order to make the likelihood of
submitting a winning bid as high as possible.
An increase in the variance of the valuations will increase the average revenues to the
seller. A greater variance in valuations will cause there to be a larger number of extreme
bids from participants. With more extreme bids, there is a greater likelihood that the
difference between the highest and lowest bid will be greater. Similarly, there is more
likely to be a greater difference between the highest valuation and the second highest
valuation. Hence, an increase in the variance of valuations also increases the surplus
captured by the successful bidder.
In the benchmark model it is optimal for the seller to impose a reserve price, as this
will cause the eventual sale price to be higher. This is a result of the fact that the
winning bid cannot come from the lower tail of the distribution governing buyers'
behavior. However, the reserve price may be below a participant's valuation but above his
bid in the absence of a reserve price. The consequence is that the marginal bidder will
raise his bid. This has a cascade effect all the way through to the bidder with the
highest valuation.
Each of the assumptions of the benchmark model can be relaxed in turn. The auction
outcomes are then seen to depend on the form chosen. The effects on the seller's ability
to maximize the sale price of the good as each assumption is relaxed are examined in the
following:
Relax Assumption 1: Risk Averse Bidders
With risk averse bidders the seller produces a larger expected revenue with a
first-price sealed bid auction than with the English or second price auction. This results
from bidders not seeing their competitors' strategy and wanting to avoid the risk of
losing the good altogether. Participants bid more aggressively, and are willing to give up
more of the surplus they would have captured in the English auction.
Insurance can play a role in auctions. The optimal auction in which bidders are risk
averse involves subsidizing high bidders who lose and penalizing low-bidders who lose.
This makes bidders prefer to win, eliciting higher bids, since they are being partially
insured. In effect participants are being penalized for trying to low-ball the auction.
This makes them bid more aggressively. That they receive a payment for their aggressive
bidding serves to insure them for having lost out on ownership of the good. Since the
auction is optimal, some of the high winning bid is used to subsidize the high bidding
losers.
Concealing the number of bidders has the effect of making the bidding more competitive. If
a participant knows that there are a large number of participants he also knows that it is
very likely that the second highest valuation is close to his own, and he will bid more
aggressively. If the number of bidders is unknown, then the risk averse bidder will assume
the number to be large.
Relax Assumption 2: Correlated Values
That bidders' valuations are independent of one another is an extreme assumption. It
is more plausible to believe that as a bidder's estimate of the value of the item rises,
she expects higher values for other bidder's estimates become more likely. In a sense, the
bidders establish a common value for the item. We say that the bidders' valuations are
affiliated.
In the most extreme common value case the item has a true unique value, albeit unknown,
about which all the bidders must make a guess. Their individual guesses differ; for
example, they differ in their ability to use the good in production or to resell the good.
In the model with common, or affiliated, values the winner is the one with the highest
guesstimate of the good's value.
The assignment of the good to the bidder who guessed its value to be greatest is known as
the winner's curse. Bridge players know that failure to make a bid is most common after
hotly contested bidding. This is an example of the winner's curse in that the successful
bidder has overvalued his hand in the process of winning the bid. In bidding for a good or
bidding for a supply contract, the true value of the good is more accurately reflected in
the average bid rather than in the bid of the eventual winner. While seeming logical, this
defies rationality in repeat situations since it assumes that bidders never learn.
The rational bidder in a sealed bid auction avoids the winner's curse by bidding what he
believes to be the second highest valuation. That is, he bids more cautiously. Hence, the
seller trying to maximize the sale price of the item should eschew silent auctions.
When bidders' valuations are affiliated, the seller's expected revenue can be ranked in
descending order by auction form from the: English auction, second price sealed bid, first
price sealed bid, and the Dutch auction.
The seller can exploit the affiliated valuations of the competitors and increase his
expected revenue by publicizing information he may have about the true value of the item.
Being aware of the winner's curse problem, competitors will tend to revise downward their
own valuation and bid more conservatively. If the seller can reveal information about the
item's value to all participants, then they will all become less cautious.
For the same reason that the seller should reveal information, she should set the reserve
price in a common value above her valuation. The reserve price serves to drive up the mean
valuation of the item.
On the other hand a bidder should lower her bid to compensate for her past inclination to
overestimate in auctions she won. She should also lower her bid to include a profit
margin. She shouldn't let the presence of more competing bidders push her into bidding too
aggressively.
Empirical work (Hendricks and Porter, 1993) confirms the theoretical conclusions where
there are information asymmetries and affiliated values. In addition, the less informed
participants are seen to be less likely to participate and the winning bids tend to be
lower. These same studies have shown that the structural bidding strategies in private and
affiliated values models can be recovered (estimated) statistically. Potentially one can
use cross sectional experience to model bid behavior in an ex ante situation.
Relax Assumption 3: Asymmetric Bidders
When bidders are asymmetric their bids are made as though they are drawing from different
distributions. In the earlier example the two participants drew their valuation from the
same distribution and for each of them the average value was the same. In the asymmetric
case the bid distribution means need not be the same. The auctioneer still awards the good
to the highest bidder, but the highest bidder need not have the highest valuation. This is
due to the fact that in part the size of the difference between the valuation and the bid
depends on the sizes of the heterogenous classes of bidders. A simple example illustrates
the case. Mr. A values the object at $65, and he will always bid a little less than this,
say $64. Mr. B thinks he can find a buyer for the object at $50 with probability ½ and a
buyer for $75 with probability ½. So the item is worth $62.50 to Mr. B, and he bids a
little less, say $61. The auction takes place and Mr. A will always win. But later a $75
buyer for the item may approach Mr. B, hence B's final value is indeed greater than A's,
who won the auction.
As in the previous example, suppose there are two classes of buyers. Their valuation
distributions are identical except for the mean. On average those in class 1 assign the
higher value to the item. Then the optimal auction favors the class of bidders with the
lower mean value. That is, the participants in class 1 reduce their bids systematically,
thinking that they need not bid so aggressively in order to beat those in the other class.
Those in class 2 will increase their bids systematically, thinking that they need to be
more aggressive in order to beat the higher valuations in class 1. The result may be that
someone from class 2 who draws his bid from the upper tail of the distribution will beat
the class 1 participants who are drawing from their lower tail.
With asymmetric bidders, the English and first price sealed bid auctions will yield
different revenues to the seller when bidders are asymmetric. In general it is not
possible to state which will be greater and so no recommendation for the seller's optimal
auction form exists. When bidders are asymmetric it is possible under the Dutch and first
price sealed bid auctions for the equilibrium (outcome) not to be efficient. That is, the
winner need not have the highest valuation. The English auction is always efficient.
Empirical work confirms the asymmetric bidders hypothesis that informed bidders will have
positive expected profits. The difference is the value of the informed firm's private
information. The participation of uninformed firms has the function of keeping the
informed firms from getting the good too cheaply.
Relax Assumption 4: Royalties and Incentive Payments
In auctioning oil rights, the government does not know ex ante the bidders'
valuations. After the auction the government can observe how much oil is extracted and
thus the true value of the tract to the buyer. The price paid by the buyer is the sum of
the bid and the royalty rate on the ex post true value of the good. The auctioneer can fix
either the bid or the royalty rate or both.
If the ex post valuation of the good is exogenous then the seller's revenue is an
increasing function of the royalty rate. A positive royalty lessens the differences in
valuations, resulting in a lower variance of valuations and higher revenue for the seller.
If the post auction valuation depends on the effort of the successful bidder then there
may be a moral hazard problem. That is, a high royalty rate will discourage the successful
bidder from exploiting the use of the item for profit. Hence the optimal royalty is always
less than 100%. The royalty rate is zero if and only if there is an infinite number of
bidders; when there is a large number of buyers, there is more likely to be a buyer who
will combine a higher purchase price and lower royalty in order to win the contract and
relieve the seller of the moral hazard problem.
When buyers are more risk averse, they will offer a higher royalty rate. This has the
effect of lowering the one time bid and shifting the risk of ex post value to the seller.
This can be seen in off-shore exploration oil tract bidding, where the purchase fee is
almost trivial, but the royalty rate (if the well comes in) is quite high.
Multi-unit Auctions:
In essence multi-unit auctions do not differ from single unit auctions. There are
however, some very specialized results (Branco, 1996 and Tenorio, 1993). In the
competitive format, in which the winners all pay a price equal to the lowest acceptable
bid, there is likely to be higher effective bidder participation, hence revenues can be
higher. At the same time, the competitive format also increases the variance of bids,
making the auction more risky for the seller.
In a two competitor auction, if the sum of bidders' valuations from giving all of the
units to one and none to the other is larger than that from any split, then it is optimal
for the seller to bundle all of the units and organize a single auction for the entire
lot. This does not seem to be generalizable to the auction with many participants (Dana
and Spier, 1994).
In multi-unit auctions the seller may want to use endogenous minimum bid announcements.
The minimum bid rule, or reserve price, will be contingent on the bidders' valuations. The
twist is that the seller cannot announce the reserve price before the competitors'
valuations are reported. In this format a winning high bidder may be confronted with a
higher reserve price than a winning low bidder.
Where each of the many winning bidders gets only one unit then the optimal auctions are
sealed bid uniform price and the discriminatory auction. In a simultaneous open auction
the seller cannot determine the bidders' private values so this is not an optimal auction.
However, where bidders may take more than one unit the optimality conditions are not
clear. There are more alternative strategies and special results, but the ones described
here illustrate most alternatives for privatization auctions.
With all of these very precise predictions from the theory one can only wonder whether
they are borne out in the real world and whether auction design matters. We begin with a
brief review of some notable mistakes in auction design and then review the recent sales
of the radio magnetic spectrum by the Federal Communications Commission.
In 1990 New Zealand chose the auction method to sell part of their spectrum for use by TV
and cellular telephone. The spectrum auction was forecast to raise NZ$240 million. On the
recommendation of an American consulting firm, they used a sealed bid second price auction
and raised only NZ$36 million. In some markets the spectrum was essentially given away.
Needless to say, the political fallout was terrible. The reason was the small number of
bidders and lack of a reserve price in a second price auction. If there is only one bidder
in a second price auction with no reserve price then that bidder will get the item for no
charge. The same essential outcome occurs when there is no serious second bidder. The
number of instances in which this happened in New Zealand was not trivial. At the very
least the New Zealand government should have required a participation fee, used an English
auction and set reserve prices.
In 1993 Australia's satellite TV services auction, two unknown firms submitted
extraordinarily high bids in first price sealed bid auctions. These same firms also
submitted a number of much lower cascading bids. When the firms defaulted on their high
bids the licenses had to be awarded to the next highest bids, which belonged to these same
firms. They defaulted sequentially until they got the price down to what they really were
willing to pay, less than half of their original bids. The problem was the lack of a
penalty for default on a winning bid.
With the examples of Australia and New Zealand behind them, the Federal Communications
Commission was more cautious in its auction design when it was charged by Congress with
the sale of the radio magnetic spectrum in the U.S. In fact, the auction was designed in
collaboration among the FCC staff, their consultants, likely competitors and their
consultants.
The wavelengths offered were those for personal communication services: pocket telephones,
portable fax machines and wireless computer networks. The Office of Management and Budget
valued this block at $10.2 billion. The reaction of the communications industry was gales
of laughter. This high estimate came in spite of the fact that the eventual size of the
market is unknown, pocket telephones in these bands will compete with existing cellular
networks, much of the technology for using this bandwidth is not yet developed, and much
investment will be needed to build the requisite infrastructure.
Prior to Congress' charge, the FCC had relied on administrative decision to assign
bandwidth. In more recent years the band width had been given away by lottery in order to
hasten the process. Lottery winners sometimes sold their licenses for a big windfall.
Needless to say, there was political pressure to capture the windfall for the Treasury.
The FCC divided the country geographically and divided the spectrum by wavelength to
create 2500 licenses. A stated goal of dividing the spectrum in this fashion and offering
the rights of use at auction was to allow aggregation of licenses for economic and
technological reasons. Efficiency was a concern since, within a region, licenses would
have substitutes. That is, a different bandwidth but in the same geographic region could
serve an equivalent function. There might also be complementarities in infrastructure and
expertise between geographic regions. Beyond economic and technological considerations,
the auction should also be designed to prevent monopolization, foster minority owned
business, promote small business and finally to assign licenses to those who value them
the most.
When it came time to design its auction mechanism, the FCC settled on an open,
simultaneous auction of all licenses in order to reduce the force of the winner's curse
and to induce participants to bid less cautiously than they would in a sealed bid auction.
This decision was made in spite of the fact that a sealed bid auction will deter collusion
more easily and will raise more revenue when the buyers are risk averse.
It was also decided to use multiple rounds of sealed bids, announcing all bids (including
bidder identities) after each round, with a minimum increment between rounds. The multiple
rounds with revealed identities and bids would allow firms to appraise their own and
competitors' bidding strategies and to estimate the likely cost of obtaining the
particular licenses and aggregations they wanted. In this way the firms would be able to
construct alternative aggregations and strategies. The multiple rounds would also offset
the winner's curse phenomenon.
Simultaneously auctioning all of the licenses at each round permitted more efficient
aggregation as firms acquire information about how others value blocks they want. The
rules left bidding open on all licenses until bidding stopped on all licenses. An activity
rule was used to insure the auction closed in a reasonable time. A deposit was required to
limit the auction to serious bidders. A bid withdrawal penalty equal to the difference
between the withdrawn bid and the bid of the eventual winner was to be imposed.
The FCC favored designated classes of bidders with set asides, price preferences, and
installment payments. This was meant to advance the goal of minority ownership. In the end
it was decided to use discounts to favor certain classes of bidders. By giving designated
bidders a discount (25%), it has the effect of driving up the bidding. A non designated
firm, when there are no discounts, will bid conservatively knowing that the minority firms
cannot compete.
Royalties on the use of the license were rejected as too difficult to enforce for
accounting reasons. Also, given that successful bidders would have to make considerable
investments in new technologies, it was decided that the moral hazard effect would be too
problematic if royalties were implemented. It was decided that reserve prices would be
used only for licenses where the number of bidders would be small.
As equilibrium came near, the winning bids were established on the high value licenses
first. After three bandwidth auctions the FCC has raised about $8.8 billion of the
projected $10.2 billion. The skeptics have been proved wrong.
In order to estimate the revenues generated in a well designed auction of liquor
licenses in Pennsylvania, one need look no further than a neighbor to the southwest, West
Virginia. On February 27, 1990 Senate Bill No. 337 was passed by the State of West
Virginia Legislature. The bill was enacted to permit the retail sale of distilled spirits
by licensees of the state. This would complete the process begun with the sale of beer and
wine through licensed, privately owned outlets.
The Liquor Licensing Board divided the state into 98 market zones. The Board then
proceeded to allocate 124 single and multiple site franchises among the zones. About 82%
of the franchises would be exclusive, conferring on the winning bidders a local monopoly.
With the full implementation of privatization there could be as many as 214 retail
outlets, an increase from 156 in the last year of the state monopoly.
The bid processes took place in August 1990, January 1991 and May 1991. Auction winners
paid $15,222,615 for the right to open retail outlets in the state and remain in operation
until their permits expire in June 2000. The winners then had to pay their annual
franchise fee and make any necessary investment in plant and equipment and merchandise
inventory before opening their doors for business. Operating expenses such as rent and
wages would be in addition to whatever was paid for the license.
Extensive supporting documents were prepared for potential bidders. The documents included
criteria for eligibility and rules for submitting bids. Competitors had to file a form
with the bureau of investigation for a brief background check. Two functions were served
by this. First, it discouraged those with a criminal record from trying to participate.
Second, it allowed the state to verify the residence of participants. While the auction
was open to both residents and non-residents, the former were given a 5% advantage in the
bidding. That is, a non-resident had to beat a resident by 5% in order to win the license.
From the theory we know that this has the effect of making non-residents bid more
aggressively.
With each sealed bid the competitors had to submit a bond valued at 25% of the highest
price offered for a license in their bid applications. In the event that a winning bidder
could not make payment, the bond would be forfeited to the state. This keeps those who are
not serious from participating in the process, and it precludes the cascading of bids as
in the Australian example.
A bid could include offers on any number of licenses, or an aggregation of licenses. In
order to win an aggregation the offer price had to beat the sum of the highest individual
bids submitted by others on each of the licenses involved. To the extent there are any
economies of large scale in retailing, allowing competitors to aggregate their choice of
licenses will foster efficiency.
The documents indicated that the state would not award a license for which there were no
acceptable bids. Furthermore, if winning bidders did not open for business within a
reasonable time, or if a license was unsold, then the state reserved the right to continue
doing business in the affected zones. In the parlance of the previous section this was
equivalent to a random, unannounced reserve price. The theoretical results indicate that a
reserve price has the effect of making bidders more aggressive. The results on announced
versus unannounced reserve prices are not clear. In the West Virginia case the lack of
announced reserve prices probably contributed to the need to go to three auctions.
In addition, detailed socioeconomic data were provided about the counties in which the
market zones were located. The data were all from the public domain and could be found in,
for example, the County and City Data Book, a well known source of marketing information.
From the population, employment, income and retail sales data the potential bidder could
make an informed judgment about the demand for alcohol beverages.
The state also furnished sales and cost information about the existing state stores in
each market zone. There was a rough correspondence between the existing state liquor
stores and available licenses. Some of the stores were quite profitable. Other stores,
largely due to low volume, had been unprofitable in the years leading up to the auction.
The competitors could use the cost and sales data to assess the likely rate of return on
their investment in a license.
The West Virginia auction had elements of both independent private values and affiliated
values. The theoretical results show that, in an affiliated values auction, the effect of
making information widely known is to increase the expected yield to the seller. The ex
post evidence is that the bidders made little use of the economic information beyond
liquor sales and total retail sales in the zone of interest.
The original intent of the Liquor License Board had been to sell all of the stores in one
round of bidding. Instead, some of the properties were withheld for reason of unacceptable
bids. The result was to cause the bidding process to mix aspects of sequential and
simultaneous auctions of multiple homogeneous goods. There is no theory with which to
model the likely resulting behavior. Two observations are worthwhile nonetheless. (See
Table 1.) First, the more valuable franchises tended to be sold in the first round in
August 1990, although there were a few exceptions. On the other hand, adjusting for the
number of outlets permitted per license shows that competitors valued the return on
investment potential about equally in the two rounds. The least desirable franchises were
clearly sold in the last round. Second, bidders participating subsequent to the first
round could infer the state's reserve prices from decisions in the early rounds. While the
more transparent reserve prices would make bidders more aggressive, the sequential nature
of the auction may have discouraged further participation both by winners in the first
round and by those who had come away empty handed. Recall that the FCC kept bidding open
on all licenses in its simultaneous auction until a price had been reached on every
license. This had the effect of allowing competitors to switch from a license which was
financially out of reach to licenses which were still priced fairly low.
|
|||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
In reviewing the winning bids it becomes apparent that there were bidders with
different kinds of financial backing. (See Table 2.) The Southland Corporation (7-11) of
Dallas and Rite-Aid of West Virginia were the largest corporate winners. Both bid on and
won numerous licenses, though their bidding behavior differed. Several regional retailers,
for example Big Bear and Giant Eagle, also bid on and won numerous licenses. Finally, many
local residents won licenses. The bidding power of the four groups differed markedly.
|
||
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Of the corporate bidders, Rite-Aid was clearly the most conservative. It is somewhat
surprising to see how conservative Southland was relative to the regional bidders. The
regional group was dominated by grocery chains seeking to leverage their existing
infrastructure into one-stop shopping for their customers. The locals may have been
capital constrained in their bidding, although economic theory suggests they should have
been able to borrow in order to compete for the more lucrative franchises.
A license restricts the number of outlets a winning bidder may have in a market zone.
There are no restrictions on the location of the outlet(s) in the zone. A license holder
may also apply for permits to distribute wine and beer. In fact, this has not been common.
A retail license holder may also obtain state and federal approval for wholesale
distribution to the restaurant trade. There are a number of cases in which the license
holder has failed to file for the wholesale permit, to the chagrin of restaurateurs.
In the year 2000, when the licenses expire, a new auction will be held. In recent
testimony before the West Virginia joint legislative committee responsible for oversight
of liquor distribution, current license owners have lobbied for a version of a 'right of
first refusal' rather than have to reenter the auction process.
In order to infer the likely success of auctioning franchise rights to liquor and wine
distribution in Pennsylvania, a regression model of the West Virginia experience was
constructed. A generic regression model of the auction is
in which i represents the observation on the ith bidder, Yi is the winning
bid, the xji are a set of variables used to explain the winning bid, ui
is an error term to capture unobservables in the auction process, and the bj are a set of
unknown parameters to be estimated. In this exercise the parameters have been estimated by
ordinary least squares (OLS).
The most important results of the exercise are reported in Table
3. As noted above, the West Virginia Liquor License Board provided interested buyers with
a book which included socioeconomic data as well as data about the existing state liquor
stores. Any of these socio-economic measures would be legitimate candidates for the right
hand side of the regression model. Surprisingly, bidders seemed to use only a small part
of this data.
In addition to the store financial data for a given market zone, the bidders also had
available the sales data for adjacent market zones, the number of outlets that could be
opened in a market zone under privatization, and data on product mix and prices. The
economics of liquor retailing are such that bidders could use either gross sales, sales
net of state taxes, or operating profit in valuing a franchise. They do not appear to have
used any of the product price and mix data in forming their bids.
The economic data included the number of retail establishments in each county and
corresponding sales, population, square miles, number of households, unemployment and per
capita income. The only data which seem to have entered bidders' valuations were retail
sales per household.
Because of the character of West Virginia and the behavior of the identifiable groups of
bidders, it was necessary to include dummy variables for urban areas, areas in which
alcohol beverages cannot be sold, and for competitors whose bidding strategy differed from
the rest of the field of competitors.
Econometric modeling is as much an art as a science, involving the judicious inclusion and
exclusion of exogenous variables on the right hand side of the equation. The last row of
table 3 reports the coefficient of determination, or R2, for the equation. In
this case the R2 shows the proportion of the variation in bid prices which can
be explained by the included exogenous variables. The R2 can be as low as zero
and as high as one. The simplest model with dummy variables for class of bidder and
whether market zone is 'dry', as well as variables for retail sales per household
and the number of outlet licenses in the bid, the proportion of variation explained is
54%.
The two rows preceding the coefficient of determination report a test statistic for the
homoscedasticity of the error term (LM for hetero) and a statistic (Condition Number) for
the extent to which the right hand side variables show co-movement (Greene (1997) at pps.
550 and 422, respectively). In every case it can be concluded that he error term in the
model is not homoscedastic. The consequence is that while the OLS estimates of the unknown
parameters are unbiased, they are not efficient.
A condition number above 20 is usually regarded as indicative of multicollinearity, or
co-movement of the right hand side variables. The second, sixth and seventh models show
multicollinearity. The consequence for estimation is that OLS estimators are unbiased, but
not measured very precisely.
In the second column the model was expanded to account for the fact that some
jurisdictions would allow competition among license holders. The second model also
includes liquor sales per existing 'state store' in the market zone. The effect of
allowing competition is to reduce the amount of the winning bid; the sign on the estimated
coefficient is negative. For every additional dollar of liquor sales by an existing state
store in the zone, the winning bid rose by $.27.
In succeeding columns additional variables were added in order to capture the potential
richness and complexity of the license valuation process made possible by the data
provided to participants. Regardless of the specification of the model, certain patterns
emerge. All other things equal, the Southland Corporation paid a substantial premium,
beyond that paid by either Rite-Aide or the regional retailers. The licenses sold in round
1 were deemed far more valuable than those sold in subsequent rounds. The round 1 premium
was only about half that paid for franchises in urban areas. In the last two columns it is
apparent that unemployment and household income did not matter much in forming the winning
bid, in the sense of statistical significance.
For purposes of assessing bidding behavior, the best model in Table 3 is in column five.
This model has one of the highest R2, the condition number is moderate, the LM
statistic is not too much out of line with the other models, and the signs on the
individual coefficients are what one would expect. Southland and the regional grocery
chains paid a premium for licenses. Licenses which were sold in the first round or were in
an urban area went at a premium. Dry areas and the presence of competitors in the zone
both reduced the bid price. Higher general retail sales, more outlets per market zone, and
previous liquor sales all elicited higher bids for a given license.
On the basis of these results one can say that, all other things equal, Southland can be
expected to pay $88,645 more for a license than other bidders. A regional chain paid
$16,596 more. Participants bid so much more aggressively on the more valuable properties
that those franchises sold in the first round accrued higher bids by $24,998. Competitors
bid $55,131 more for a license in an urban market than for a license in a rural market,
all other things equal. If a market zone was wholly dry, then the valuation of the license
was reduced by $65,627. Because some of the franchise licenses permitted multiple outlets,
a variable indicating the potential number of stores available to the winner was included.
Each additional outlet associated with a winning bid served to raise the winning price by
$129,756. By the same token, not all franchises conferred a local monopoly on the winner.
For each additional competitor allowed into a market zone, the value of the license fell
by $16,786. For every additional dollar of retail sales per household in the county in
which the franchise was located the winning bid price rose by $7.10. Finally, for every
dollar increase in sales net of taxes, competitors raised their bids by $.25.
To illustrate how one could use these results for Pennsylvania, consider the franchise
rights for the four Liquor Control Board stores in Cheltenham Township in Eastern
Montgomery County. This is an urban area in the sense applied in the West Virginia study.
Suppose in one scenario that a bidder is allowed to buy a single franchise permitting four
outlets; there are no competitors permitted in the zone. The winning bidder, we can safely
assume, will be a chain grocery operator of magnitude similar to Southland Corporation.
Since Cheltenham is a valuable location, we be sure it would sell in the first round of
any auction. Retail sales in Cheltenham last year were about $34,000 per household, and
combined gross sales by the four stores were $6,962,742. Plugging all of this information
into the regression model yields a forecasted winning bid of $2.2 million dollars. This
may, in fact, underestimate the true value at auction since the West Virginia residents
were bidding on a system which had previously privatized its wine distribution, while
Pennsylvania has only privatized beer sales. On the other hand, wine sales are included in
the Pennsylvania sales figure.
Using the regression results it is possible to give some ball park figures for the auction
value of the wine and liquor franchise rights in Pennsylvania. Cheltenham accounts for
about .8% of the combined wine and liquor sales in the state. Extrapolating from the
winning bid in the last paragraph one might expect to realize about $270 million for the
franchise rights in the entire state. Even if one used only the regression coefficient for
the liquor sales variable, one could expect the state to receive $170 million in franchise
rights. The sale of merchandise inventory and physical plant would add more to these
estimates. And one should be mindful that, as the monopoly wholesaler the state's alcohol
beverage tax base is bounded only by the work ethic of the new retailers, the tax rate and
retail demand.
Table 3: Bidding for West Virginia Liquor Licenses |
|||||||
Eqn |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
Constant |
-306255 (-6.78) |
-264250 (-6.05) |
-231154 (-4.66) |
-264228 (-5.61) |
-258377 (-5.50) |
-216303 (-3.07) |
-151366 (-1.84) |
South-land |
121884 (2.68) |
101802 (2.36) |
85564 (1.91) |
90704 (2.02) |
88645 (1.99) |
81862 (1.73) |
97453 (2.13) |
Rite- Aide |
13716 (.54) |
||||||
Region |
68525 (1.91) |
29915 (.83) |
16596 (.45) |
||||
Local |
-22251 (-.95) |
||||||
Round 1 |
26488 (1.18) |
24998 (1.10) |
27605 (1.24) |
27618 (1.25) |
|||
Urban |
51439 (1.20) |
58462 (1.36) |
55131 (1.27) |
57025 (1.34) |
60457 (1.43) |
||
Dry |
-73073 (-1.85) |
-64534 (-1.70) |
-64236 (-1.71) |
-70255 (-1.86) |
-65627 (-1.72) |
-69960 (-1.87) |
-75480 (-2.02) |
Outlets |
136308 (8.67) |
127616 (8.34) |
127234 (8.35) |
130741 (8.78) |
129756 (8.47) |
136951 (9.22) |
136371 (9.22) |
Comp |
-10112 (-1.15) |
-18100 (-1.79) |
-18845 (-1.86) |
-16786 (-1.58) |
-37436 (-2.75) |
-33974 (-2.46) |
|
Retail |
13.45 (5.21) |
7.65 (2.61) |
7.51 (2.58) |
7.31 (2.50) |
7.10 (2.41) |
7.15 (2.43) |
9.07 (2.65) |
Liquor Sales |
.27 (3.97) |
.26 (3.85) |
.26 (3.89) |
.25 (3.59) |
.16 (1.91) |
.16 (2.01) |
|
Income |
-9.07 (-1.02) |
||||||
Profit |
.27 (2.09) |
||||||
Unemploy- ment |
-148 (-.03) |
||||||
LM for Hetero |
355.7 |
428.6 |
350.6 |
364.1 |
417.8 |
308.9 |
306.6 |
Condition Number |
9.01 |
67.21 |
13.63 |
13.44 |
13.43 |
20.41 |
31.75 |
R2 |
.54 |
.60 |
.61 |
.61 |
.61 |
.63 |
.63 |
Conclusions
In light of economic theory and the experience of West Virginia and the FCC, it is
possible to make some recommendations for the design of an auction of wine and spirits
retail distribution licenses in Pennsylvania.
1. Reserve prices on the franchises should be announced ex ante.
2. All relevant economic data should be made available to all competitors prior to the
auction.
3. All accounting data for each existing store should be made available to each
competitor.
4. Franchise rights should be geographically exclusive, though not necessarily correspond
to existing stores.
5. Competitors should be required to post a bond to be forfeited in the event that they
are not able to make payment on their winning bid.
6. The licenses should be auctioned in a simultaneous, multi-round auction. All licenses
are to be in play until a high bid is reached on all licenses.
7. The amount and identity of the high bid on each license should be announced at the end
of each round.
8. In order to remain in the bidding each competitor must post a minimum increment bid on
at least 25% of the licenses in which she had previously expressed interest.
Barring cataclysm, and assuming underlying similarities with West Virginia, such an
auction could raise in excess of $200 million in ten year franchise rights, on top of the
annual tax (and profit) revenue already collected by the Commonwealth.
Bibliography
Branco, Fernando, 1996, "Multiple Unit Auctions of an Indivisible Good", Economic
Theory, Vol. 8, Pps. 77-101.
Buck, Andrew J. and Simon Hakim, 1991, Privatizing Liquor Sales in Pennsylvania,
The Commonwealth Foundation for Public Policy Alternatives, Harrisburg, PA, June.
Dana, James D. and Kathryn E. Spier, 1994, "Designing a Private Industry: Government
Auctions with Endogenous Market Structure", Journal of Public Economics, Vol.
53, No. 1, Pps. 127-147.
Fitzgerald, J.L. and H.A. Mulford, 1993, "Privatization, Price and Cross-Border
Liquor Purchases", Journal of Studies on Alcohol, Vol. 54, No. 4, July, Pps.
462-464.
Greene, William H., 1997, Econometric Analysis, third edition, Prentice-Hall, New
Jersey.
Hendricks, Kenneth and Robert Porter, 1993, "Bidding Behavior in OCS Drainage
Auctions: Theory and Evidence", European Economic Review, Vol. 37, Pps.
320-326.
Holder, Harold, 1993, "The State Monopoly as a Public Policy Approach to Consumption
and Alcohol Problems: A Review of Research Evidence", Contemporary Drug Problems,
Vol. 20, No. 2, Summer, Pps. 293-322.
Laffont, Jean-Jacques and Quang Vuong, 1993, "Structural Econometric Analysis of
Descending Auctions", European Economic Review, Vol. 37, Pps. 329-341.
McAFee, R. Preston and John McMillan, 1987, "Auctions and Bidding," Journal
of Economic Literature, Vol. 25, No. 2, June, pps. 699-738.
McAfee, R. Preston and John McMillan, 1996, "Analyzing the Airwaves Auction", Journal
of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 10, No. 1, Winter, Pps. 159-176.
McMillan, John, 1994, "Selling Spectrum Rights", Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Vol. 8, No. 3, Summer, Pps. 145-162.
Milgrom, Paul, 1989, "Auctions and Bidding: A Primer", Journal of Economic
Perspectives, Vol. 3, No. 2, Summer, Pps. 3-22.
Riley, John G., 1989, "Expected Revenue from Open and Sealed Bid Auctions", Journal
of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 3, No.2, Summer, Pps. 41-50.
Swaine, Margaret, 1995, "The Case for Privatization", An Information
Symposium on Alcohol Privatization/Deregulation, Nov. 20, Toronto, Canada.
Tenorio, Rafael, 1993, "Revenue Equivalence and Bidding Behavior in a Multi-unit
Auction Market: An Empirical Analysis", Review of Economics and Statistics,
Vol. 75, No. 2, May, Pps. 302-314.
Wang, Ruqu, 1993, "Auctions versus Posted Price Selling", American Economic
Review, Vol. 83, No. 4, September, Pps. 838-851.